Can Counterfeits of Coins That Never Existed Function as Money?

Counterfeit 1899 Peruvian dinero. (Image from Luis Ortega-San-Martín and Fabiola Bravo-Hualpa article.)

What counts as money is an interesting topic. For instance, in Macroeconomics, Chapter 14, Section 14.2 (Economics, Chapter 24, Section 24.2, and Essentials of Economics, Chapter 16, Section 16.2), we discuss whether bitcoin is money (spoiler alert: it isn’t).  

Of the four functions of money that we discuss in Chapter 14, the most important is that money serves as a medium of exchange. Anything can be used as money if most people are willing to accept it in exchange for goods and services.  In that chapter, we mention that at one time in West Africa cowrie shells were used as money. In the early years of the United States, animal skins were sometimes used as money. For instance, the first governor of Tennessee received an annual salary of 1,000 deerskins.

In a famous article in the academic journal Economica, economist Richard A. Radford who had been captured in 1942 by German troops while fighting with the British Army in North Africa described his experiences in a prisoner-of-war camp. The British prisoners in the camp developed an economy in which cigarettes were used as money:

“Everyone, including nonsmokers, was willing to sell for cigarettes, using them to buy at another time and place. Cigarettes became the normal currency .… Laundrymen advertised at two cigarettes a garment …. There was a coffee stall owner who sold tea, coffee or cocoa at two cigarettes a cup, buying his raw materials at market prices and hiring labour ….”

In Chapter 24, in end of chapter problem 1.8, we note that according to historian Peter Heather, during the time of the Roman Empire, German tribes east of the Rhine river used Roman coins as money even though Rome didn’t govern that area. Roman coins were apparently also used as money in parts of India during those years even though the nearest territory the Romans controlled was hundreds of miles to the west. Again we have an example of something—roman coins in this case—being used as money because people were willing to aceept it in exchange for goods and services even though the government that issued the coins didn’t control that area.

Even more striking case is the case of Iraqi paper currency issued by the government of Saddam Hussein. This currency continued to circulate even after Saddam’s government had collapsed following the invasion of Iraq by U.S. and British troops. U.S. officials in Iraq had expected that as soon as the war was over and Saddam had been forced from power, the currency with his picture on it would lose all its value. This result had seemed inevitable once the United States had begun paying Iraqi officials in U.S. dollars. However, for some time many Iraqis continued to use the old currency because they were familiar with it. According to an article in the Wall Street Journal, the Iraqi manager of a currency exchange put it this way: “People trust the dinar more than the dollar. It’s Iraqi.” In fact, for some weeks after the invasion, increasing demand for the dinar caused its value to rise against the dollar. Eventually, a new Iraqi government was formed, and the government ordered that dinars with Saddam’s picture be replaced by a new dinar. Again we see that anything can be used as money as long as people are willing to accept it in exchange for goods and services, even paper currency issued by a government that no longer exists.

Finally, there is the case of the coin shown at the beginning of this post. The coin looks like the dineros—small denomination silver coins—issued by the Peruvian government. But the coin is dated 1899, a year in which the Peruvian government did not issue any dineros. An analysis of one of these coins by Luis Ortega-San-Martín, Fabiola Bravo-Hualpa, and their students at the Pontifical Catholic University of Peru showed that it was made of copper, nickel, and zinc, in contrast to deniros from other years, which where made primarily of silver with a small amount of copper. They concluded that the coin was a counterfeit made around 1900:

“It is our belief that this counterfeit coin was not made as a numismatic rarity to deceive modern collectors … but rather to be used as current money (its worn state indicates ample use) …. [C]ounterfeiters usually make common coins that do not draw attention expecting them to pass unnoticed.”

In other words, as long as people are willing to accept counterfeit coins—which they likely will do if they do not recognize them as being counterfeit—they can serve as money. In fact, even if coins are easily recognizable as being counterfeit, they might still be used as money—particularly in a time and place where there is a shortage of government issued coins. In the British North American colonies, there was frequently a shortage of coins. Some people would clip small amounts off gold and silver coins, either selling the metal or having it minted into coins. The clipped coins, while not actually counterfeit, contained less precious metal than did unclipped coins, yet they continued to be used in buying and selling because of the general shortage of coins.

Leave a comment